Pigouvian Tax Model in Global Climate Policy: Applications, Implications, Drawbacks, and Policy Recommendations with a Concentration on the Carbon Tax

This paper delves into the outcomes of current uses of the Pigouvian tax model in recent years to address and mitigate environmental concerns such as climate change, resulting in a carbon tax, in various countries. The primary objective of this paper is to analyze and determine the efficacy of the Pigouvian tax model as a global policy – especially concerning carbon dioxide emission tax regulations – by using a thematic case study analysis with policy implications to assess the model's applications, drawbacks, and implications. We examine the economic impact, social equity, political feasibility, regional disparity, and environmental effectiveness of carbon taxation through five case studies: a hypothetical tax model in the Philippines, Germany’s carbon pricing, Canada’s political response to a carbon tax, British Columbia’s regional divide on carbon taxation, and an analysis of the Kyoto Protocol.

Published by 

 on 

April 21, 2025

Inquiry-driven, this article may reflect personal views, aiming to enrich problem-related discourse.

Heading

Card Title

Lorem ipsum dolor sit amet conse adipiscing elit

Card Title

Lorem ipsum dolor sit amet conse adipiscing elit

Card Title

Lorem ipsum dolor sit amet conse adipiscing elit

Card Title

Lorem ipsum dolor sit amet conse adipiscing elit

Support

ll. Introduction

In this paper, we analyze the implementation of the Pigouvian tax model and carbon tax in several regions, exploring five key themes: economic impacts, social impacts, political feasibility, regional disparity, and the environmental effectiveness of carbon taxation. Through exploration of the five key themes, this paper serves as a comprehensive review of the carbon tax and serves as a comprehensive guide to policy recommendations to alleviate potential drawbacks of carbon taxation in a given country, as well as introducing applications of carbon taxation, and offering implications. 

The Pigouvian Tax Model

The Pigouvian tax model was first introduced by economist Arthur C. Pigou when he considered that market transactions could create a negative externality borne on individuals not directly involved in the transaction of products.  Increasingly, governments worldwide are adopting this tax model to require producers, and in certain policy models, consumers, to bear the social cost of consumerism to encourage subsidies towards reducing the negative externalities of production and product cycles that create an overabundance of carbon dioxide in excess. The model's positive implications reflect a bright future for humanity's manner of solving the negative externalities associated with non-sustainable development. However, its harrowing drawbacks reveal the steadiness at which economists must continue to assess a proper cost-benefit analysis to determine if the Pigouvian tax model is feasible as a climate policy for sustainable development.  

The Carbon Tax

In the Pigouvian model, the carbon tax is a government-set price on greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions per ton directed at intense-emitting businesses and industries, aiming to counter and encourage subsidies to diffuse the social cost of greenhouse gas emissions production, to later incentivize technological advancement and reduced emissions through a market-based approach and price-based competition. This policy has, at the time of this study, been implemented in 27 countries; of those, this study explores Germany; Canada; an analysis of a Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) model assessment of a carbon tax’s effects on the economy in the Philippines ; and an analysis of the Kyoto Accords, on a case-by-case basis to uncover a comprehensive analysis of carbon taxation's effects and to provide consequential policy recommendations. 

lll. Methodology

The research methodology involves analyzing five distinct case studies of carbon taxation. Through each case study, a thematic lense will be employed. Within each lense, we will assess the case studies key findings, applications, drawbacks, implications, and provide policy recommendations, as well as considerations for future research. Applications, drawbacks, and implications apply to those of the carbon tax in the context of the thematic view and the associated country. The economic impact analysis employs a Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) economic model using economic data and industrial output data from global carbon tax proposals to define the effects and implications of carbon taxation in the Philippines. The social equity analysis reviews income distribution and energy price data in Germany. The political feasibility study includes interviews and public opinion analysis from British Columbia's carbon tax experience. While the regional disparity and public opposition analysis draws from political opposition to the tax in the rural north of British Columbia with quotes and resources from local council minutes, local council resolutions, media coverage, open ended interviews with politicians, and published materials. The environmental analysis will be derived in an assessment of the shortcomings of the Kyoto Accords and acknowledgement of the potential of carbon taxation in being a more effective proponent and commitment to reducing emissions. 

IV. Thematic Overview

In order to serve a comprehensive understanding of the effects of carbon taxation and the takeaways, this comprehensive review serves to give concrete policy recommendations that all countries must consider in lieu of implementing a carbon tax. This paper breaks down the analysis into five key themes: economic impact, social equity, political feasibility, regional disparity, and environmental effectiveness. Each of these themes is examined through different case studies, allowing for a detailed exploration of how carbon taxes impact different sectors of society and how their success is shaped by various external factors. As well as providing insights into manners of adjusting existing policy to mitigate the potential negative implications of carbon taxation and what currently stands in the way of it becoming a feasible solution to climate change all countries can support with minimal negative implications. 

V. Case Study: Economic Impacts in the Philippines

Introduction to the Study

Erwin L. Coron, a research economist at the Center for Global Trade Analysis at Purdue University, published a 2008 study, "Tariff reductions, carbon emissions, and poverty: an economy-wide assessment of the Philippines," which examined the effects of carbon taxation in conjunction with trade liberalization. His findings indicate that while a carbon tax raises oil-based energy costs, it also promotes cleaner energy adoption, contributing to poverty and inequality alleviation when paired with tariff reductions.

Key Findings 

Ultimately, Coron's study finds that carbon taxation can benefit working-class individuals through tax breaks and lower prices without significantly harming industrial output when combined with trade liberalization. 

Although carbon taxation has negative implications like increased energy costs and inflation, these can be mitigated by the accompanying trade liberalization. As the cost of carbon-intensive energy sources, such as coal and oil, increases, non-carbon-intensive energy costs significantly decrease, making clean energy accessible more than before and for low-income people. This study illustrates the potential for a carbon taxation to reduce social inequality when combined with trade liberalization. 

VI. Applications

Promoting Clean Energy and Technological Innovation

Given the study's finding that non-carbon energy sources become cheaper, the  study shows that the implementation of a carbon tax, due to market-based competition and demand, promotes clean energy and spurs technological innovation towards meeting the demand for cheaper energy, within this model, energy that is independent of fossil fuels. 

Vll . Drawbacks

Economic Impacts on Households and Inequality

Specifically, Coron's study explores how carbon taxation impacts economic sectors and the cost of living, particularly for working-class households. For instance, he warns that implementing a carbon tax without trade liberalization could disproportionately burden lower-income groups by increasing fuel and energy costs, reducing purchasing power, and driving inflation; without the benefits of reduced tariffs, the tax alone raises the price of fuel and energy, worsening economic disparity. However, proponents argue that while the cost of carbon-intensive energy sources like coal and oil increases, non-carbon-intensive alternatives become more affordable, invariably making clean energy more accessible.

Carbon tax revenues can reduce income taxes and alleviate financial burdens.  He further notes, "cost…fell for all households as consumer goods became cheaper…," (2008, p. 28), highlighting that reduced tariffs, combined with carbon taxation, increase purchasing power for lower-income populations. Moreover, Coron finds that "carbon taxation did not significantly affect the manufacturing sector's performance…an increase in all exports," (2008, p. 29), demonstrating that the tax does not necessarily hinder industrial productivity or economic growth. 

However, Coron acknowledges that a carbon tax alone could lead to "a marginal reduction in consumption and overall output...a higher import demand...lower domestic production (0.2 per cent) resulting from the increase in relative energy prices,” (2008, p. 26). As local energy prices rise, reliance on imports may increase, potentially affecting domestic job availability. 

Additionally, the economist notes, "agricultural workers and blue-collar industrial workers experienced the lowest increase in disposable income, as they benefited less from the carbon tax revenue recycling scheme," (2008, p. 9), meaning that lower-income workers could see fewer benefits compared to higher earners, exacerbating inequities in income disparity, as lower-income workers will bear the brunt of the cost of the carbon tax, as fixed discretionary income of low-income workers is not flexible enough to easily endure an energy transition, due to initially high costs, however, over time the inability to afford a transition to clean energy will result in high tax that endures the multiplier effect, effectively indebting low-income workers at disproportionately high rates, while high-income workers find the initial energy transition accessible, and do not face the economic burden of a high tax rate. He also notes, "a carbon tax could…affect fuel prices… people's expenditures and livelihoods,” (2008, p. 2), acknowledging that higher fuel costs could strain household budgets and the broader economy.

Business Practice Implications

The study also highlights a potential tradeoff: "The fall in the nominal price of capital and wages (0.01 and 0.49 per cent respectively) allowed firms to some extent, to substitute capital and labour for energy" (2008, p. 9). This indicates that businesses may offset increased energy costs by cutting wages and reducing labor demand instead of investing in cleaner technology. Such an outcome raises concerns about potential inequitable business practices under a carbon tax framework.

Vlll. Implications

Economic Consequences of Carbon Taxation

The study identifies both positive and negative consequences of a carbon tax on the Philippine economy. Negative impacts include the increased price of natural gas and higher costs for gas and oil, which can reduce consumer purchasing power and contribute to inflation. Without tariff reductions, these rising costs place a more significant financial burden on consumers. However, the study also highlights that trade liberalization can offset the adverse effects of taxes. A carbon tax can help lower poverty, improve welfare, and decrease CO2 emissions when combined with reduced tariffs. While the cost of carbon-intensive energy sources like coal and oil rises, the price of non-carbon-intensive energy decreases significantly, making clean energy more accessible—particularly for low-income households. And Coron points out the "price of non-carbon energy inputs…electric…became…cheaper since they were exempted from the carbon tax," (2008, p. 8), demonstrating that carbon taxation encourages renewable energy adoption by making it more cost-effective. 

IX. Policy Recommendations: Supporting Low-Income Households

Duly, then, Coron's study explores a carbon tax's impact, emphasizing its potential benefits and challenges, particularly for low-income households. While the tax would increase the cost of carbon-intensive energy sources like coal and oil, it would also make non-carbon energy sources more affordable, encouraging a shift to cleaner alternatives. To support low-income households, the study suggests implementing trade liberalization or reducing tariffs to lower the cost of consumer goods and make clean energy alternatives more competitively priced. It also proposes using the revenue from the carbon tax to reduce income taxes, thus increasing disposable income, and implementing programs to provide subsidies or tax returns for low-income households to offset higher living costs.

To mitigate the economic burden of carbon taxes, policies like trade liberalization or reduced tariffs could make clean energy alternatives more accessible for low-income households by reducing the cost of consumer goods and support the availability of clean energy alternatives at competitive prices.  This potential policy shift would make carbon taxation less economically intimidating for countries wary of a carbon fee's economic impacts. However, considering the sensitivity of foreign trade policy regarding geopolitics is of considerable importance. 

Further Promoting Clean Energy and Technological Innovation

To support a smooth transition to cheaper, cleaner energy under a carbon tax, governments should invest in programs that promote renewable energy technologies to accelerate clean energy transitions to eventually phase out dependence on fossil fuels and lower energy costs over time, benefiting both the environment and the economy,  especially for lower-income households burdened by rising energy costs. Carbon tax revenue could reduce income taxes and, thereby, increase disposable income, so governments could implement a revenue recycling program that puts carbon tax revenue back into subsidies or tax returns for low-income households to offset the increased cost of living due to higher energy prices. 

The study suggests that carbon taxes can incentivize businesses to adopt new technologies, so governments can create programs to support businesses in adopting green technologies and transitioning their workforce, even including funding for enterprises investing in sustainable technologies and retraining programs for workers in carbon-intensive industries to reduce inequity and incentivize economic revitalization. 

X. Further Research

However, further studies are necessary to distinguish the separate effects of carbon taxation from tariff reductions, as this study focuses on their combined impact. Additionally, real-world case studies could clarify whether the Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) model used in this research accurately reflects practical outcomes, given the potential influence of unforeseen variables, such as the model’s basis in the theoretical structures in which some data values are based on educated inferences (Ibqual and Siddiqui, 2001). 

XI. Case Study: Social Equity in Germany 

Introduction to the Study

The study by Maike Venjakob, Oliver Wagner, and Brite Schnurr, researchers at the Wuppertal Institut, titled "Can a CO₂ Tax Be Socially Just? Analysis of the Social Distribution Effects of the German CO₂ Taxation," aims to assess the social impact of Germany's energy transition, particularly the implications of the newly introduced carbon taxand Renewable Energy Act and whether it can be considered "socially just." 

Key Findings 

Through data analysis and correlation between energy consumption and income, as well as the economic burden of the energy transition on low-income households, single-family homes, and DINK (Dual Income, No Kids) households, the study reveals that the energy transition under the Renewable Energies Act was unjust to low-income households. However, it suggests that redistributing CO2 tax revenues could mitigate this burden despite the inevitability of rising energy prices and their impact on families.

Xll. Applications

Promoting Energy Efficiency

The carbon tax aims to use tax revenue to incentivize energy efficiency. The policy encourages sustainable behavior by rewarding households that adopt energy-saving appliances such as heat pumps while potentially offsetting tax burdens. If structured correctly, the carbon tax could be a socially just mechanism that balances climate action with economic fairness. In a global context, this suggests that if a worldwide carbon tax were implemented, rising energy prices could be mitigated through revenue reimbursement strategies that promote equity for lower-income families. 

Xlll. Drawbacks

Social Impact and Energy Poverty

The carbon tax and Renewable Energies Act had socially unjust effects, disproportionately harming low-income, working-class people, by making it challenging to meet their basic needs due to rising energy prices. The act's distributional issues affected low-income households, which faced higher energy costs, while wealthier individuals benefited from increased energy efficiency, leading to lower relative energy prices. 

Venjakob et al. explain, "That latter can avert a situation where the poorer population cannot satisfy their basic needs due to rising energy prices as a result of CO₂ pricing" (2023, p. 1). This suggests that CO₂ pricing could make poorer populations vulnerable to energy poverty. The authors further highlight, "Even in a rich country such as Germany, energy poverty is significant, as evidenced, for example, by a large number of meter disconnections, which mainly occur in socially disadvantaged neighborhoods as consequences of numerous problems rooted in the low income of families" (2023, p. 1). This demonstrates that energy poverty remains a pressing concern even in developed countries. The study reveals, "In 2021, nearly 235,000 electricity disconnections and nearly 27,000 gas disconnections occurred in Germany, generally as a result of payment arrears” (2023, p. 3). This underscores the extent of energy insecurity in Germany and reinforces the argument that for a carbon tax to be socially viable, its effects on household costs must be considered. Even before the carbon tax's introduction, the Renewable Energies Act alone left 235,000 people unable to pay their electricity bills on time.

Economic Burden on Low-Income Households

Figure 1. Development of electricity prices compared with various income levels since 2008 (Venjakob et al., 2023, p. 3). 

Venjakob et al. further state, "Since 2000, household customers have had to pay the Renewable Energies Act levy. It rose very slowly from 0.19 cents in 2000 to 1.16 cents per kilowatt hour of electricity in 2008 and 1.32 cents in 2009. After that, however, it increased significantly: between 2010 and 2014, it more than tripled. Since then, it has remained relatively constant at a high level" (2023, p. 3). This illustrates the long-term trend of increasing electricity rates under the Renewable Energies Act and emphasizes the financial burden of financing climate-friendly power generation, as illustrated above in Figure 1. Rising energy costs disproportionately burden low-income households, potentially trapping them in a cycle of poverty. Because these households lack the financial resources to invest in energy-efficient appliances, they remain stuck with high energy expenses. This finding underscores the importance of ensuring that climate policies are equitable and do not exacerbate poverty.

The study also reveals that energy prices have risen faster than wages, particularly affecting 20% of employees in the low-wage sector, including full-time workers such as geriatric nurses and firefighters. This indicates that many hardworking citizens are significantly burdened. Additionally, the study points out, "High-income households have more opportunities to save energy costs by purchasing more economical appliances or better thermal insulation than poor households" (2023, p. 6). This explains the disparity in energy costs between income groups: wealthier households can afford energy-efficient appliances that reduce consumption and lower their overall energy expenses, whereas low-income families cannot. 

Figure 2. Net Equivalent income per person and year by family status and employment type. Own calculation. (Venjakob et al., 2023, p. 5)

Venjakob et al. also states, referencing Figure 2, "According to [23], the limit of EUR 16,300 represents a critical threshold below which special expenses, such as those due to rapidly increased energy costs, can easily pose a risk of poverty. In order to earn a net equivalent income of EUR 16,300 per person per year, for a family with two children, two adults together need to work 60 h per week (75%) if they are paid a low wage, as illustrated” (2023, p. 5). This suggests that middle-income families may also be at risk of poverty due to rising energy costs, making them part of the vulnerable population affected by the carbon tax. The study emphasizes that the economic stability of the working class should be a priority, as it is socially unjust to impose such a heavy financial burden on families.

XIV. Policy Recommendations: Revenue Recycling

The study suggests implementing a revenue recycling program, through direct payments, tax reductions, or targeted subsidies, to redistribute carbon tax revenue and thereby reduce inequality to alleviate the financial burden riding energy prices had on low-income households. The Renewable Energies Act has also contributed to higher prices for low-income households, while wealthier households have been able to invest in energy-efficient technologies. To remedy this, the government should provide subsidies and incentives to help low-income households transition to energy-efficient technologies, ultimately reducing their annual carbon tax burden.

By directing carbon tax revenues toward these measures, the government can ensure that climate policies are socially just and that the financial burdens of the energy transition are fairly distributed. A well-designed revenue recycling mechanism would help offset the adverse effects of rising energy prices and increase social equity, particularly for low-income households.

Venjakob et al. supports this potential solution: "The possibilities for returning the revenues of a CO₂ tax include, above all, the per capita flat rate (also climate dividend, climate bonus, energy transition bonus, etc.) …this is paid out…in a lump sum to all citizens…. Due to the fact that poorer households generate lower CO₂ emissions…reimbursement would cause financial redistribution from richer to poorer households" (2023, p. 9). This suggests that a revenue reimbursement strategy could increase social equality by allowing low-income households to invest in energy-efficient appliances. 

XV. Future Research

Further exploration of revenue recycling shortcomings is essential to developing effective policy recommendations

XVl. Case Study: Political Feasibility in Canada

Introduction to the Study

Beyond theoretical principles and applications, evaluating the political feasibility of a carbon tax and how it has fared politically in the past is essential. This evaluation reveals the political drawbacks of carbon taxation. Kathryn Harrison's review, "A Tale of Two Taxes: The Fate of Environmental Tax Reform in Canada," analyzes interviews with professionals and politicians during a public oppositional movement against the passage of British Columbia's carbon tax. The study suggests that associations and misinformation in public opinion shape carbon taxation stances more than research. The study's methodology, which included over 33 verified interviews, strengthens the credibility of these findings. 

Key Findings

The study underscores the negative consequences of political strategy determining the fate of the carbon tax rather than evidence-based research. In a global context, the success of the carbon tax may depend primarily on how voters perceive it, which is often shaped by political discourse rather than its actual merits. 

XVll. Applications

Public Perceptions and Policy Viability

Harrison notes, "…decision to pursue…carbon tax…reflected…personal commitment of party leaders" (2023, p. 401), revealing that political will, rather than the efficacy of the policy, can determine the fate of the carbon tax. This demonstrates how political motivations can override the policy's intrinsic merits, contributing to the political unfeasibility of carbon taxation, particularly in economically conservative countries. The study highlights how politicians' self-interest and public misconceptions often determine carbon taxation's success or failure, making it difficult for such policies to gain traction.

XVlll. Drawbacks

Misinformation and Political Strategy in Carbon Tax Decisions

The claim that misinformation and political strategy determine carbon taxation success is supported by instances where misinformation against carbon taxation, designed to rally support for a political candidate, effectively created opposition to the carbon tax, even when the opposing claim was false. 

Political Opportunism: The Carole James Example

Harrison cites an interview with a politician who states, "I am ashamed of Carole James…for using 'axe the tax' as a political opportunity" (2023, p. 393). This highlights how politicians, driven by self-interest such as re-election, can exploit misconceptions about carbon taxation to mislead the public and garner support instead of informing the electorate about the truth through transparent campaigns.

XlX. Implications

Economic Concerns vs. Environmental Goals

Harrison explains, "…an economic recession…next election…voters…preoccupied with economic, rather than environmental…issues" (2023, p. 384), demonstrating that political landscapes can heavily influence the success of carbon tax policies. This suggests that carbon taxes are often swayed by public opinion and political agendas rather than their efficiency or necessity. She also notes, "…carbon taxes…reduced both parties' popularity…offering a cautionary tale concerning the fate of 'good policy' motives absent electoral backing" (2023, p. 384), illustrating that carbon taxes can be politically unpopular, leading politicians to avoid them for fear of backlash and loss of support. Harrison points out, "…voters…did not believe the government's reassurances that the tax was revenue neutral" (2023, p. 393). This illustrates how misinformation can shape voters' perceptions and influence the political landscape. 

XX. Policy Recommendations: Political Effectiveness

To ensure the carbon tax's success globally, it must be politically strategic, garnering public support by clarifying its benefits and minimizing divisiveness.

The study highlights how political factors such as standing, affiliations, and opportunism impacted the feasibility of implementing the carbon tax in Canada. The study delves into the negative consequences of political strategy in determining the fate of carbon taxation rather than research-backed evidence. Specifically, the example of Carole James implies that politics and won public voters are not always influenced by truth and may vote based on misinformation.  In a global context, this means that the vitality of the carbon tax is based primarily on how a voter interprets it on a simple basis. This study found potential for the carbon tax to be contended by politics and make politicians be held accountable for their irresponsible misconduct.  

Because the nature and efficacy of carbon taxation are somewhat complicated, this means that in the future, for the carbon tax to be more politically adept and a more assertive politically "good"  policy, it must be accompanied by campaigns that simplify the carbon tax as a system that is promoting technological innovation, free market economics, or revenue recycling or neutrality depending on the specific carbon taxation policy method. 

Reframing the Carbon Tax: Shifting Public Perception

More importantly, to make the policy more appealing to the working people, and most importantly, seem like a good political strategy for politicians to jump on the bandwagon and garner public opinion, is to move away from the word "tax" because it has negative associations with non-revenue neutrality. As evidenced by the research paper, in Canada's history, it has been seen that the carbon tax recommended was misconstrued not to be revenue neutral even though it was revenue neutral; this resulted in much public opposition to the policy that led to significant public outrage over the carbon tax because people believed they would have to pay more taxes as a result of this policy,  even though it was not going to affect the amount of tax dollars that the public was going to pay,  per definition of revenue neutral. 

Gradual Implementation for Public and Economic Stability

This demonstrates that in a global context, in the future, if the carbon tax has the great conviction to succeed as a policy internationally, it must show significant consideration towards being politically strategic in garnering public support and seeming to be an instant winner of public support if it desires not to be passed or regarded more highly politically than cap and trade which is not as effective or move away from being divisive which was a massive negative for business support. This paper showed that the carbon tax has the potential to pass through curtains of public misinformation and political unreceptiveness and manipulation. The government can improve public understanding and support by clarifying that carbon taxes are not designed to increase overall tax burdens but to redistribute revenue for social and environmental benefits. The fact that carbon tax policies face backlash during economic recessions when voters prioritize immediate economic concerns over long-term environmental goals should show that constituents value comfort, so it must be prioritized that carbon taxes have minimal financial impact on households and businesses, and gradually increase over time, so that an economic recession may not directly lead to the lack of favorability of a carbon tax. The gradual implementation of the carbon tax will also reduce public concerns during economic uncertainty while still advancing environmental goals and providing businesses and households time to adapt. 

XXl. Case Study: Regional Disparity and Public Opinion in British Columbia

Introduction to the Study

In another study, authored by Kathryn Harrison and Chelsea Peet, "Historical legacies and policy reform: diverse regional reactions to British Columbia's carbon tax," the historical legacy of policy reform and the diverse regional reactions to British Columbia's carbon tax are explored. 

Key Findings

This study demonstrates how popular opinion, often influenced by ill-informed beliefs, negative connotations, and a lack of knowledge, resulted in significant resistance to the carbon tax in the northern region. Furthermore, it reveals a disparity in how the carbon tax would impact prices for individuals in the rural north versus the south. Two perspectives emerge in the study: one emphasizing the role of ill-informed beliefs driven by a culture of reduced political engagement, increased resource usage, and suburban and rural living, resulting in strong opposition to the carbon tax in Northern British Columbia. The other highlights the regional disparity, where the Northern regions bear more significant burdens due to cultural reliance on industry, resource-intensive vehicles, and business survival. These diverse perspectives suggest that the regional divide in acceptance of the carbon tax may reflect disparities between income levels or lifestyles, often shaped by factors like geography and cultural heritage rather than individual choice.

The report covers the historical legacy of policy reform and the diverse regional reactions to British  Columbia's (Canada) carbon tax. This review delved into the implications of the regional divide between North and  South due to a cultural disparity and divide. It revealed that historical legacies of policy reform,  negative connotations towards the word "tax" in carbon tax impact public opinion, and that cultural lack of knowledge of the true implications and structure of a carbon tax, including tax cuts,  shows how the carbon tax is opposed due to speculation rather than concrete evidence. This demonstrates that cultural impacts may make it difficult for the public to accept a carbon tax globally, given how the common people may reject the idea of additional taxes, especially in a system where the popular vote significantly impacts policy. 

XXll. Drawbacks

Regional Disparities 

Primary author Peet contends, "Many northern British Columbians must work in the harsh environments of the resource sector, and fuel consumption is not a choice. It is a necessity. Northern British Columbians already pay up to ten percent more than their urban counterparts for fuel for basic transportation and home heating. Many northern British Columbians must endure long-distance travel over remote roads, harsh weather, and hostile environments to see their doctor or to access basic services such as school, shopping, and work. The proposed carbon tax will create a domino effect of disproportionately higher taxes through transportation and heating costs for school, universities, colleges and hospitals in the colder, northern and eastern region of the province" (2012, p. 4). This explains how differences in energy use are driven by geography and suggests that the carbon tax may not be socially just, especially for those in the North who already pay more for living costs than their Southern counterparts.

Cultural and Geographic Factors

Peet also notes, "…the provincial government all reported that commuters in the Lower Mainland suburbs, rather than rural British Columbians, would pay the most under the carbon tax…" (2012, p. 1). This reveals the disparity between regions, showing that the carbon tax disproportionately affects the Lower Mainland's commuter suburbs, which rely heavily on car and gasoline usage. Additionally, Peet adds, "Despite that, and despite the conclusion of the various analyses discussed above (i.e., that residents of Lower Mainland commuter cities like Coquitlam and Abbotsford would be hardest hit by the provincial carbon tax), internet and documentary searches for their discontent fail to turn up any critical public statements made by mayors or participants in town council debates. There was remarkably little opposition from commuter cities…" (2012, p. 5). This highlights the disparity in political opposition between regions, suggesting that cultural shifts in engagement influence the vocal opposition to the tax.

XXlll. Implications

Oppositions Driven by Misconceptions

However, the benefits of the carbon tax were not as publicly visible. As Peet states, "The word' tax,' an instrument that tends to be unpopular with voters, is visible in the title. In contrast, the corresponding benefits of the policy--namely, tax cuts--are delayed and much less visible" (2012, p. 3). This reflects how the negative connotation of the word "tax" led to widespread opposition, even though the tax's benefits were not immediately apparent to the public. Peet also explains, "Moreover, given the psychological phenomenon of loss aversion (Kahneman et al., 1991), even if carbon tax revenues are fully recycled to voters via tax cuts, one would not expect voters' appreciation of the tax deductions to match their resentment of the new taxes" (2012, p. 3). This insight is valuable in understanding why the carbon tax faced resistance despite its potentially positive impact.

Revenue Neutrality Misunderstood

Peet further explores the issue of revenue neutrality, noting, "Indeed, the claim of revenue-neutrality may be perceived as politically disingenuous by voters who cannot see how a carbon tax can accomplish anything if the government is giving all the money back…" (2012, p.  2). This highlights how the complexity of the carbon tax's structure and the lack of understanding about its revenue neutrality contributed to public opposition.

The study also addresses how the historical legacy of taxes in British Columbia shaped public opinion, with Peet concluding, "That the purpose of a carbon tax, in contrast to other, more familiar taxes, is not to raise revenues but, rather, to create incentives for consumers to change their behavior can be confusing to voters…" (2012, p. 2). This indicates that the carbon tax's intended purpose was misunderstood, further fueling resistance.

Political Engagement and Misinformation

This report examines the historical legacy of policy reform and the diverse regional reactions to British Columbia's carbon tax, revealing how ill-informed beliefs, negative associations with the term "tax," and a lack of understanding about the carbon tax's structure and benefits led to significant resistance in the northern regions. The study also highlights a cultural and geographical divide, with the Northern regions experiencing a disproportionate burden due to their reliance on industry and resource-intensive lifestyles. This cultural opposition is rooted in misconceptions rather than concrete evidence, suggesting that cultural impacts may hinder the global acceptance of the carbon tax. However, a positive takeaway is a need for greater public education and engagement to promote understanding of the benefits of carbon taxes, particularly tax cuts. Duly, then, greater political engagement and education can help address misconceptions and build support for the carbon tax. Governments should also consider regional adjustments to the carbon tax to account for differences in fuel consumption and socio-economic conditions. This could reduce opposition from regions such as Northern British Columbia, where the tax disproportionately impacts daily life. Furthermore, emphasizing the economic benefits of the carbon tax, including how it is revenue-neutral, and clarifying its environmental and economic advantages will help shift the narrative and garner public support. Educational campaigns should focus on these points, using evidence-based reassurances to address public concerns and promote the long-term benefits of the carbon tax.

Policy Recommendations 

Shifting Public Perspective through Public Engagement 

In a global context, this implies that if a global carbon tax is to be implemented, there must be a focus on ensuring that the public understands that the tax is an incentive for cleaner energy transitions.  Additionally, in a global context, these institutes, politicians and policymakers may want to move away from using the word "tax" to avoid misrepresenting this climate policy (carbon tax). Additionally, in a global context, the study implies the importance of understanding different regional and cultural perspectives, which ensures that constituents in an area can play a part in the political system to speak about their opinions on policies like the carbon tax in order for an interchange of ideas to take place in which government officials come out with a better understanding of how to mitigate harm to their constituents and continues (in the north in this case) walk away with a better understanding of the true implications of a policy like the carbon tax. Especially given that the lack of engagement with local officials is what led to a public outrage because misinformation was rampant and people were not involved with their political system,  which could be solved through increased access to political and educational programs and greater political involvement among constituents so they can play a part in governing their community. In the future, misguided beliefs should be addressed through proper press release statements informing and addressing the public with evidence-based reassurances that it would be in the best interests of the people it affects.

Regional Adjustments 

Additionally, governments should consider regional adjustments to the carbon tax to address geographic and socio-economic differences that affect fuel consumption and consider inequality. In this study, in the north, increased fuel consumption was more of a necessity than a choice due to harsh weather and long distances, which shows that the carbon tax disproportionately affected certain regions, exacerbating existing inequalities, so a regional-based policy approach would ensure equity and reduce opposition from regions like  Northern British Columbia, where the carbon tax disproportionately impacts daily life.  Governments should also emphasize the economic benefits of carbon taxation to shift the narrative towards the positive impacts of the policy. Educational campaigns could also be developed to focus on how the revenue-neutral structure of the tax works and the environmental and economic benefits it generates, particularly for future generations, to build support for the carbon tax and ensure it is not misunderstood or misrepresented. Governments should also encourage addressing misconceptions through targeted public relations efforts, including press releases, town hall meetings, and educational programs that offer evidence-based reassurances.

XXIV. Case Study: Economic Effectiveness in the Carbon Tax. vs. Cap-and-Trade

Introduction to the Study

Further, carbon taxation's influence on greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions is important in evaluating its functionalities and exigencies. For instance, Robert J. Shapiro's study "Addressing the Risks of Climate Change: The  Environmental Effectiveness and Economic Efficiency of Carbon Taxes, Compared to Emissions  Caps and Tradable Permits" undertakes such an evaluation. 

Key Findings

In his study, Shapiro asserts that carbon taxes are more environmentally effective than an alternative cap and trade permit system enacted by the Kyoto Accords in 1997. This argument strongly supports the high international advocacy for the carbon tax. Shapiro's primary perspective concerns how the carbon tax incentivizes more significant technological advancements and increases sustainability in countries,  especially developing ones. An alternative to Shapiro's perspective, however, argues that the carbon tax's free-market economic framework [which includes revenue that can, through government funneling, be directed into sustainable infrastructure and energy sources] renders it impossible to firmly predict the environmental effects of CO2 emissions and the like. Shapiro counters by expressing that the tax would provide a 'continual incentive to reduce the costs of carbon abatement…" (2007, p. 24). 

XXV. Applications

Reducing Carbon Emissions

Shapiro asserts that "carbon taxes…economically-efficient and politically-feasible…persuade the world's major energy producing and energy consuming countries to adopt them” (2007, p. 27). Such remarks exhibit strength as they demonstrate that the carbon tax's emission-reducing efficacy is greater than its perceived potential due to its political feasibility and economic efficiency. His remarks also show how the positive effects of the carbon tax can lead to greater acceptance of carbon taxation among countries and greater environmental return from a greater stretch of participation. 

Incentivizing Technological Advancement

Shapiro also claims, "A carbon tax would…reduce greenhouse gas emissions and provide powerful incentives for technological progress…" (2007, p. 27). This claim asserts that taxation can be a stronghold for companies to drive technological advancements such as clean energy reform and reduced emissions. 

The study found that the carbon tax successfully reduced emissions in various countries by incentivizing technological innovation while maintaining flexibility, which enabled a more balanced cost-benefit analysis that helped stabilize energy prices. This stability, in turn, increased global support for the policy and encouraged emissions-reduction efforts. 

XXVl. Drawbacks

Predicting Carbon Reduction

However, the extent of the efficiency in doing so is difficult to quantify. Shapiro notes its "drawback is that no one can predict how much a particular carbon tax will reduce emissions" (2007, p. 8). This notion challenges previous claims, highlighting the uncertainty of the carbon tax's efficacy due to heavy reliance on free-market principles. Nevertheless, Shapiro adds that "governments can raise or lower their carbon taxes, year by year, to achieve the desired reduction in emissions" (2007, p. 8). This suggests that despite initial unpredictability, emission reductions can be achievable, and in doing so, demonstrates that carbon pricing can effectively lower greenhouse gas emissions and combat climate change. Still, an issue emphasized is the difficulty in predicting the carbon tax's effectiveness in emission reduction. The tax's success, in particular, depends on revenue cycling, which tends to vary by country, some might prioritize reinvestment in sustainable development more than others, for instance. 

XXVll. Implications of the Kyoto Accords

The framing of the Kyoto Accords, was highlighted and demonstrated the justifiable nature of  the U.S.’s rejection of the Kyoto Accords due to concerns about corruption and economic inefficiency. Shapiro's study suggests that the accords, while a significant step towards global climate cooperation in the early 2000’s, placed disproportionate burdens on larger nations. 

XVlll. Policy Recommendations

In a global context, the study implies that the carbon tax should be pushed as an international climate policy that effectively tackles climate change with more efficiency in reducing greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. Policymakers should also prioritize transparent communication about the tax's goals and the system's flexibility to adapt to changing circumstances. Shapiro's study reveals how the Kyoto Accords reliance on a cap-and-trade system could lead to volatility in energy prices and undermine incentives for technological advancement; and recommends carbon taxation over a cap-and-trade system. 

XXIX. Future Research

In order to strengthen Shapiro's argument, however, future research should be oriented around county and national-level case studies that evaluate real-world impacts of carbon taxes on emissions reduction, as Shapiro's current study, admittingly, lacks empirical evidence beyond deductive economic reasoning.

XXX. Conclusion

Effective, equitable, and economically viable climate policy action is a direct path to mitigating climate change. Its negative implications and implementing direct policy recommendations are absolutely essential to driving collective international climate action. 

This paper explored the economic, social, political, and environmental feasibility of carbon taxes by examining the various case studies by Coron, Venjakob et al., Harrison, Peet, and Shapiro, raising attention to the applications and practicalities of carbon taxation while acknowledging its implications and drawbacks and offering the best possible policy recommendations to accommodate for its shortcomings in various countries to ensure that carbon taxation remains a viable tool for reducing climate change with considerate comprehensive considerations across all facets of understanding, from economic to social to environmental. While carbon taxes present significant potential for reducing emissions and promoting green innovation, their success depends heavily on economic effects, social effects, political strategies, regional effects, public opinion,  and effectiveness. Given the urgency of climate change, this study urges action to make carbon taxes a viable and attractive option for countries, ensuring they play a crucial role in securing a livable future. 

The economic impacts of carbon taxation in the Philippines model mainly highlight the necessity of ensuring that carbon taxes are introduced by targeted economic policies, like tariff reductions or trade liberalization, to ensure that they don't stifle economic growth or place undue pressure on vulnerable populations. The Philippine Computable General Equilibrium model (CGE) teaches us that economic impacts must be considered carefully to prevent social unrest and political opposition, particularly in developing countries where economic concerns are paramount.

Through Germany's approach, Venjakob et al. emphasized a combination of carbon taxation and social policies, such as revenue recycling, to alleviate the unjust economic burden increased prices have on low-income households. Carbon taxation must not be divisive and must be implemented with thoughtful, inclusive policies to be a unifying force in climate action. 

Harrison's analysis of British Columbia's carbon tax shows that shaping public opinion is vital to moving the public to consider scientific fact over political strategy. We must not allow political strategy and misinformation to determine the fate of environmental policies often. 

The regional disparities highlighted by Peet urgently acknowledge how geographic and cultural factors have influenced the public divide regarding carbon taxation policies. Exceedingly, there is a significant divide, a regional disparity, between the more urbanized southern regions of British Columbia and the resource-dependent northern regions, where fuel consumption is often a necessity rather than a choice. The regional disparity is exacerbated by a lack of political engagement and understanding, which stresses the need for region-specific adjustments and communication strategies within carbon pricing policy that underline and assess the unique economic and geographic conditions of different areas, predominantly rural or resource-dependent regions. 

Shapiro's study demonstrates how carbon taxes more effectively incentivize technological innovation and reduce greenhouse gas emissions than cap-and-trade systems. 

The lessons learned from these five case studies point to several key policy recommendations in which governments must consider and adapt to the effects of carbon taxation to ensure it does not adversely affect the economy or vulnerable populations. Public education surrounding carbon taxation misconceptions is also imperative; regional adjustments are essential to ensure the tax is fair and equitable, especially for communities facing disproportionate burdens. To ensure effectiveness, carbon taxes must be monitored to ensure they reduce carbon emissions at adequate efficiency by being adjusted for optimization. The global success of carbon taxes depends on the flexibility of the policy to adapt to minimally affect the economy and social inequality, as well as on international cooperation. 

Ultimately, we must make the carbon tax as appealing and effective as possible to ensure the future of our nature. It remains one of the best paths toward ending climate change, and only by making it a practical, transparent, and equitable tool can we harness its full potential for global economic, environmental, and sustainability. 

Glossary 

Pigouvian Tax: A tax on market transactions that create negative externalities. Externalities: Costs or benefits that affect parties not directly involved in a transaction. Product Cycles: The stages of production and distribution of a product.

Social Cost: The negative impact of economic activities on individuals or society. Market: A system where supply and demand meet. 

Carbon Tax: A tax on fossil fuels or greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions intended to reduce the  emission of carbon dioxide. 

Tariff: A tax on imported goods. 

Purchasing Power: The ability to buy goods and services and the extent to which you can buy  with the money you have on hand.  

Inflation: The general increase in prices and reduction in purchasing power.  Economic Disparity: Drastic differences in income or wealth. 

Computable General Equilibrium Modelling (CGE): a class of economic models that use actual  economic data to estimate how an economy might react to changes in policy, technology or other  external factors.  

Revenue-recycling: Revenue recycling refers to mechanisms through which income generated  from carbon taxation is earmarked and returned back to society.  

Trade Liberalization: Removing barriers to trade. 

Welfare: State support for citizens. 

Energy Poverty: Lack of access to energy services. 

Renewable Energies Act: The Renewable Energy Sources Act (EEG) is a series of German laws  that originally provided a feed-in tariff (FIT) scheme to encourage the generation of renewable  electricity.  

Expenditure: Spending on goods and services. 

Revenue Neutrality: Offsetting revenue loss with other measures that offsets or ‘neutralizes’  added cost burdens.  

Kyoto Accords: An international agreement that aimed to reduce carbon dioxide emissions and  the presence of greenhouse gases (GHG) in the atmosphere.  

Cap and Trade: A system for controlling carbon emissions and other forms of atmospheric  pollution by which an upper limit is set on the amount a given business or other organization  may produce but which allows further capacity to be bought from other organizations that have  not used their full allowance. 

Bibliography 

Coron, Erwin L. “Tariff reductions, carbon emissions, and poverty: an economy-wide assessment  of the Philippines.” ASEAN Economic Bulletin, vol. 25, no. 1, Apr. 2008, pp. 20+. Gale  Academic OneFile,  link.gale.com/apps/doc/A183423018/AONE?u=fl_ap&sid=bookmark 

AONE&xid=dfc769e6. Accessed 9 Oct. 2024. 

Harrison, Kathryn. “A tale of two taxes: the fate of environmental tax reform in Canada.” The  Review of Policy Research, vol. 29, no. 3, May 2023. Gale Academic OneFile,  http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1541-1338.2012.00565.x. Accessed 16 Nov. 2024. 

Ibqual Zafar and Rizwana Siddiqui. “Critical Review of Literature on Computable General Equilibrium Models.” MIMAP TECHNICAL PAPER SERIES, no. 9, January 2001. Accessed 8 March 2025. 

Peet Chelsea and Kathryn Harrison. “Historical legacies and policy reform: diverse regional  reactions to British Columbia's carbon tax.” BC Studies vol. 173, 2012. Gale Academic  OneFile.link.gale.com/apps/doc/A293544600/AONE?u=fl_ap&sid=bookmarkAONE&xi d=a2b26555. Accessed 11 Nov. 2024 . 

Shapiro, Robert J. “Addressing the Risks of Climate Change: The Environmental Effectiveness  and Economic Efficiency of Emissions Caps and Tradable Permits, Compared to Carbon  Taxes.” Feb. 2007. https://api.semanticscholar.org/CorpusID:150935375. Accessed 21 Oct.  2024. 

Venjakob, Maike, Oliver Wagner, and Brite Schnurr. “Can a CO2 Tax Be Socially Just? Analysis of the Social Distribution Effects of the German CO2 Taxation. Energies of the German Taxation.” Energies, vol. 16, no. 17, Aug. 2023. Gale Academic OneFile, http://dx.doi.org/10.3390/en16176232. Accessed 14 Oct. 2024.

No items found.

Brandy Gutierrez

2024 Fall Fellow

Brandy Gutierrez is a highschooler in 12th grade interested in economic development, international development, foreign policy, poverty studies, inequality studies, and environmental and climate policy.

Author's Profile

More from this edition

No items found.

A Comparative Analysis of Climate Change Policies: Denmark & The United States

In

Journal Vol. 5

on

April 21, 2025

Climate change is one of the most pressing global challenges, demanding coordinated action from leaders and policymakers worldwide. As countries struggle to adapt and mitigate the far-reaching, severe consequences of climate change, the policies they implement play a crucial role in shaping sustainability and the future. This paper compares and contrasts the climate change policies of two nations—the United States and Denmark—by analyzing the effectiveness, equity considerations, and political contexts of the United States’ Inflation Reduction Act and Denmark’s Climate Action Plan. The Inflation Reduction Act is the most significant and recent climate-focused piece of legislation put forward by the United States. Since President Trump’s term began in January 2025, multiple executive orders unraveling the work of the Biden-Harris agenda on climate change have been signed. At this point in time, it’s still too early to understand the full environmental and economic scope of what President Trump's orders could mean for the world. Nevertheless, the paper will briefly discuss what his approach to fossil fuel companies are during his time in office. In the United States, federalism is a defining feature of environmental policy, with the strongest forms of climate action emerging from the state government level, leading to varying policies from state to state. As such, this paper will specifically analyze the domestic environmental policies in Vermont in comparison to the international environmental policies in Copenhagen, Denmark. While Vermont’s green initiatives set it apart and ahead of the rest of the United States, Denmark’s ambitious emissions goals and climate policies set an example for the rest of the world. With a focus on renewable energy, carbon taxes, and technological innovations, Denmark’s approach to fighting climate change offers a blueprint for sustainability for the world to model. By comparing Denmark to the United States, one can better envision a 21st-century green economy rooted in sustainability and justice.

more